This article is from the source 'nytimes' and was first published or seen on . It last changed over 40 days ago and won't be checked again for changes.

You can find the current article at its original source at https://www.nytimes.com/2018/10/08/business/economic-science-nobel-prize.html

The article has changed 8 times. There is an RSS feed of changes available.

Version 6 Version 7
2018 Nobel in Economics Is Awarded to William Nordhaus and Paul Romer 2018 Nobel in Economics Is Awarded to William Nordhaus and Paul Romer
(about 7 hours later)
WASHINGTON — The 2018 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science was awarded on Monday to a pair of American economists, William D. Nordhaus and Paul M. Romer, for their work highlighting the importance of government policy in fostering sustainable economic growth. WASHINGTON — The Yale economist William D. Nordhaus has spent the better part of four decades trying to persuade governments to address climate change, preferably by imposing a tax on carbon emissions.
Mr. Nordhaus was honored for pioneering the assessment of the economic impact of climate change, including his advocacy for governments to tax carbon emissions. Mr. Romer was honored for his work on the role of policy in encouraging technological innovation. His careful work has long since convinced most members of his own profession, and on Monday he was awarded the 2018 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in recognition of that achievement.
Mr. Nordhaus, 77, is a professor at Yale. Mr. Romer, 62, is a professor at New York University. But Professor Nordhaus sadly noted that he hadn’t convinced the government of his own country.
The announcement of the award came on the same day that a United Nations panel on climate change released a report warning of dire consequences from climate change and urging governments to respond to the problem with greater urgency. The Nobel Prize committee said that its choice of laureates underscored the need for governments to cooperate. “The policies are lagging very, very far miles, miles, miles behind the science and what needs to be done,” Professor Nordhaus said shortly after learning of the prize. “It’s hard to be optimistic. And we’re actually going backward in the United States with the disastrous policies of the Trump administration.”
“The message is that it’s needed for countries to cooperate globally to solve some of these big questions,” said Goran K. Hansson, secretary general of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. Professor Nordhaus shared the prize with Paul M. Romer, an economist at New York University whose work has demonstrated that government policy plays a critical role in fostering technological innovation.
Mr. Romer said he and Mr. Nordhaus shared a sense of optimism. The award was announced just hours after a United Nations panel said large changes in public policy were urgently needed to limit the catastrophic consequences of rising temperatures. The prize committee said its choice of laureates was meant to emphasize the need for international cooperation.
“One problem today is that people think protecting the environment will be so costly and so hard that they want to ignore the problem and pretend it doesn’t exist,” he said at a news conference following the announcement. “Humans are capable of amazing accomplishments if we set our minds to it.” “The message is that it’s needed for countries to cooperate globally to solve some of these big questions,” said Goran K. Hansson, the secretary general of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences.
On Monday, Mr. Romer said that he did not answer his phone when it rang in the morning, figuring it was a spam call. Then he checked caller ID and saw the call was from Sweden. So he called back and, after waiting on hold, learned that he’d won the Nobel Prize. That was described as a rebuke to the Trump administration by some proponents of stronger action to confront climate change. Under President Trump, the United States has pulled back from global efforts to limit climate change, and it has moved to reduce controls on pollution.
Mr. Nordhaus, 77, graduated from Yale and then earned a doctorate in economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1967. That same year, he returned to Yale as a member of the economics faculty, and he has remained there ever since. “Any Nobel Prize linked with global climate change will inevitably be seen as an international critique of Mr. Trump’s outspoken opposition to domestic and international climate change action,” said Robert Stavins, head of the Environmental Economics Program at Harvard.
In the 1960s and the 1970s, amid rising concern about pollution, economists began to argue that taxation was the most effective solution: The government should charge people for polluting. Professor Romer, for his part, offered a more optimistic take on the challenges confronting society, saying that his work showed that governments could drive technological change. He noted the success of efforts to reduce emissions of ozone-depleting chlorofluorocarbons in the 1990s.
Mr. Nordhaus became an early advocate for the taxation of carbon emissions. He argued that the best way to limit emissions was to calculate the cost of a fixed level of emissions and then require companies or governments to pay for those costs. “One problem today is that people think protecting the environment will be so costly and so hard that they want to ignore the problem and pretend it doesn’t exist,” Professor Romer said at a news conference after the announcement. “Humans are capable of amazing accomplishments if we set our minds to it.”
The Nobel Prize committee cited Mr. Nordhaus for his work in showing that “the most efficient remedy for problems caused by greenhouse gases is a global scheme of universally imposed carbon taxes.” The day began with a little comedy, as the Swedes struggled to contact the winners.
Mr. Nordhaus also was honored for his role in developing a model that allows economists to analyze the costs of climate change. His work undergirds a new United Nations report on the dangers of climate change, released Monday in South Korea. The report warns that avoiding significant damage will require the international community to quickly coordinate changes in environmental regulation on a scale that has “no documented historic precedent.” Professor Romer said he heard his phone ring, twice, in the early morning hours, but he did not answer because he assumed it was a spam call. Then he checked caller ID and saw the call was from Sweden. So he called back and, after waiting on hold, learned he had won the Nobel Prize.
Mr. Romer, 62, sought to explain the role of technological advances in driving economic growth. His work was inspired by a desire to understand the remarkable acceleration in growth that began with the Industrial Revolution. Professor Nordhaus said he slept in, only learning that he won the prize when his daughter called.
Economists had traditionally treated the arrival of new ideas as manna from heaven: obviously important but beyond the control of public policy. Mr. Romer’s big idea was to argue that policymakers could foster technological innovation, for example, by investing in research and development and by writing patent laws that provided sufficient rewards for new ideas without letting inventors permanently monopolize those rewards. “She said, ‘It’s so nice!’” Professor Nordhaus recounted, “and I said, ‘What?’”
He argued that national differences in such public policies helped to explain differences in economic growth rates. Professor Nordhaus, 77, graduated from Yale in 1963, earned a doctorate in economics from MIT in 1967 and then returned to Yale as a member of the economics faculty. He has been there ever since.
Mr. Romer said in an interview that the value of his work was in being precise about a broadly intuitive idea. In the 1970s, amid rising concern about pollution, economists including Professor Nordhaus began to argue that taxation was the most effective remedy: The government should require polluters to pay for damage to the environment and to public health. The idea remains broadly popular among economists.
“It helps to see connections that weren’t obvious at first,” he said. “There is basically no alternative to the market solution,” Professor Nordhaus said Monday.
In particular, Mr. Romer’s work elucidated the value of participating in larger communities. While a given part of the world might be able to meet its own material needs, larger communities tend to produce more ideas, which can then be broadly shared. To assess the costs of climate change, including crop failures and flooding, Professor Nordhaus developed an economic model he called the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy model, or DICE.
“It isn’t just that we exchange mutton for port,” Mr. Romer said. “Probably the most important part of globalization is the sharing of knowledge, that billions of people can all pursue in parallel.” The name, he said, “consciously aimed to suggest that we are gambling with the future of our planet.”
In advocating for his ideas about growth, Mr. Romer has sometimes courted controversy, telling one interviewer in the 1990s, “I’m quite happy to offend everyone.” The approach developed by Professor Nordhaus remains the industry standard. It undergirds the new United Nations report on the dangers of climate change, released Monday in South Korea, which warns that avoiding significant damage will require the international community to quickly coordinate changes in environmental regulation on a scale that has “no documented historic precedent.”
In a 2015 essay, he criticized some rival growth theorists for the sin of “mathiness,” which he described as the use of math to obscure rather than clarify underlying ideas. He argued that some economists were dressing up political beliefs in the language of science. “The style that I am calling mathiness lets academic politics masquerade as science,” he wrote. The Nobel committee cited Professor Nordhaus for showing “the most efficient remedy for problems caused by greenhouse gases is a global scheme of universally imposed carbon taxes.”
In 2016, Mr. Romer was named chief economist of the World Bank, a prestigious perch for a development economist. But he resigned 15 months later, in January 2018, after suggesting the bank’s positive evaluation of Chile’s economic policies had been influenced by political considerations. Professor Nordhaus has also worked on broader issues related to economic growth. In a paper published in 1996, he showed that traditional measurements of growth understated improvements in the quality of life.
Mr. Romer is the son of Roy Romer, a former governor of Colorado. He earned a doctorate in economics from the University of Chicago in 1983, and then began his career as an academic. He used the example of artificial light, calculating that the amount of work required to produce a given amount of illumination had decreased much more sharply than the standard measures of the price of light. His technique was also unusual: He created his own fires, for example acquiring an authentic Roman oil lamp to measure the light it produced.
This is the 50th time that the prize in economics has been awarded. Professor Romer, 62, was honored for loosely related work on the determinants of economic development.
Mr. Nordhaus and Mr. Romer have long been mentioned as possible recipients of the prize, but they were not obvious candidates to be honored together. Economists who studied the broad workings of the economy understood that the pace of innovation was influenced by human behavior, but they had not mastered the details. As a result, they often treated innovation as manna from heaven, and not a legitimate subject of public policy.
Richard H. Thaler was recognized for his pioneering work in establishing that people are predictably irrational that they consistently behave in ways that defy economic theory. He is credited with persuading many economists to pay more attention to human behavior, and many governments to pay more attention to economics. Professor Romer received his bachelor’s degree and doctorate from the University of Chicago. He has spoken publicly about his struggles with dyslexia, joking that he found the strength to keep writing by telling himself, “If Neil Young can make a living as a singer, I can make a living as a writer.”
James P. Allison and Tasuku Honjo were awarded the Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine last Monday, for a discovery that the body’s immune system can be used to attack cancer cells. He said he was attracted to growth theory because he was intrigued by the acceleration of innovation that is a hallmark of the modern era. In papers in the 1980s and 1990s, Professor Romer developed the idea that nations could foster innovation by investing in research and by writing laws governing the ownership of intellectual property that rewarded innovation, but not excessively.
Arthur Ashkin, Gérard Mourou and Donna Strickland were awarded the Nobel Prize in Physics on Tuesday for developing tools made of light beams. Dr. Strickland is just the third woman to win the physics prize. He argued that differences in policy helped to explain differences in economic growth.
Three scientists were awarded the Nobel Prize in Chemistry on Wednesday: Frances H. Arnold of the U.S., who received half the prize, and George P. Smith and Gregory P. Winter who shared the other half. They won for tapping the power of evolutionary biology to design molecules. In an interview, Professor Romer said the value of his work was in being precise about a broadly intuitive idea. “It helps to see connections that weren’t obvious at first,” he said.
The Congolese gynecological surgeon Denis Mukwege and the former ISIS captive Nadia Murad were awarded the Nobel Peace Prize on Friday “for their efforts to end the use of sexual violence as a weapon of war and armed conflict.” In particular, his work elucidated the benefits of scale. While a community might meet its own material needs, larger communities will still tend to produce more and better ideas. “It isn’t just that we exchange mutton for port,” Professor Romer said of the benefits of international trade. “Probably the most important part of globalization is the sharing of knowledge that billions of people can all pursue in parallel.”
The Nobel Prize in Literature has been postponed. The institution that chooses the laureate is embroiled in a scandal involving allegations of sexual misconduct, financial malpractice and repeated leaks a crisis that led to the departure of several board members and required the intervention of the Swedish king. Two laureates might be named next year. Read about last year’s winner, Kazuo Ishiguro. In advocating for his ideas about growth, Professor Romer has sometimes courted controversy, telling one interviewer in the 1990s, “I’m quite happy to offend everyone.”
In a 2015 essay, he criticized some other economists, including those with different ideas about the determinants of growth, for the sin of “mathiness,” which he described as the use of math to obscure rather than clarify underlying ideas. “The style that I am calling mathiness lets academic politics masquerade as science,” he wrote.
In 2016, Professor Romer was named chief economist of the World Bank, a prestigious perch for a development economist. But he resigned 15 months later, in January 2018, after suggesting the bank’s positive evaluation of Chile’s economic policies had been influenced by political considerations.
There are broad commonalities in the contributions of Professor Romer and Professor Nordhaus.
The prize committee emphasized that both men, in their work, have argued that markets are imperfect and that government intervention can improve outcomes.
Joshua Gans, an economist at the University of Toronto, said both men also had helped to reduce the barriers to government intervention: In the case of climate change, by estimating the costs of inaction; in the case of innovation, by estimating the benefits of action.
“Each showed how a careful accounting of economic forces can lead to progress,” Mr. Gans wrote.
But both men still struggle to sell their ideas to policymakers.
Professor Romer, who is the son of Roy Romer, a former Colorado governor, said economists needed to cultivate and husband a reputation as “umpires in the fact business” rather than openly campaigning.
Professor Nordhaus lamented that that approach did not seem to be enough.
“We understand the science, we understand the effects of climate change,” he said. “But we don’t understand how to bring countries together.”