This article is from the source 'guardian' and was first published or seen on . It last changed over 40 days ago and won't be checked again for changes.

You can find the current article at its original source at http://www.theguardian.com/business/2018/oct/18/eu-members-should-be-wary-of-stealing-londons-super-sized-financial-sector

The article has changed 7 times. There is an RSS feed of changes available.

Version 3 Version 4
EU members should be wary of stealing London's super-sized financial sector EU members should be wary of stealing London's super-sized financial sector
(5 days later)
As the UK’s Brexit negotiations stumble on, other European countries are using the uncertainty about the future regulation of the continent’s financial markets to tempt firms and activities away from London.As the UK’s Brexit negotiations stumble on, other European countries are using the uncertainty about the future regulation of the continent’s financial markets to tempt firms and activities away from London.
The French have been particularly active in support of Paris, but Frankfurt, despite lukewarm support from the government in Berlin, has not been far behind. And other cities such as Luxembourg City, Dublin and Amsterdam have laid out their own welcome mats. Bankers have not been so popular for a decade or more.The French have been particularly active in support of Paris, but Frankfurt, despite lukewarm support from the government in Berlin, has not been far behind. And other cities such as Luxembourg City, Dublin and Amsterdam have laid out their own welcome mats. Bankers have not been so popular for a decade or more.
But should other cities really wish to emulate London and become a global financial centre? Do they know what is good for them and their national economies?But should other cities really wish to emulate London and become a global financial centre? Do they know what is good for them and their national economies?
The 2008 global financial crisis has prompted some rethinking about the pros and cons. Hosting a major financial centre is, of course, unambiguously good for Porsche dealerships, upmarket champagne bars and table dancing clubs. But some argue that the drawbacks in terms of the effect on the rest of the economy are too serious to ignore.The 2008 global financial crisis has prompted some rethinking about the pros and cons. Hosting a major financial centre is, of course, unambiguously good for Porsche dealerships, upmarket champagne bars and table dancing clubs. But some argue that the drawbacks in terms of the effect on the rest of the economy are too serious to ignore.
Andy Haldane, the Bank of England’s chief economist, has described the banking industry as a “pollutant”, at least in part. “Systemic risk,” he says, “is a noxious by-product” that “risks endangering innocent bystanders within the wider economy”. Some countries, the UK among them, continue to bear “the social costs to the general public from banking crises”.Andy Haldane, the Bank of England’s chief economist, has described the banking industry as a “pollutant”, at least in part. “Systemic risk,” he says, “is a noxious by-product” that “risks endangering innocent bystanders within the wider economy”. Some countries, the UK among them, continue to bear “the social costs to the general public from banking crises”.
But it may be argued that regulatory reform, particularly the far higher capital requirements established by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision for systemically significant banks, has reduced the risk of incurring those costs. Research has shown that so-called tier one capital ratios above 13% cut the risk of banking collapses sharply. The risk can never be reduced to zero but the stress testing carried out by regulators shows that most major banks can now survive very extreme economic shocks. The Bank of England models a 4.7% contraction in GDP and a 33% fall in house prices, and so far the banks have survived.But it may be argued that regulatory reform, particularly the far higher capital requirements established by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision for systemically significant banks, has reduced the risk of incurring those costs. Research has shown that so-called tier one capital ratios above 13% cut the risk of banking collapses sharply. The risk can never be reduced to zero but the stress testing carried out by regulators shows that most major banks can now survive very extreme economic shocks. The Bank of England models a 4.7% contraction in GDP and a 33% fall in house prices, and so far the banks have survived.
Other studies, however, point to other adverse side-effects from hosting a super-sized financial sector. For example, Stephen Cecchetti and Enisse Kharroubi of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), have argued that an excessively large financial sector damages productivity and growth.Other studies, however, point to other adverse side-effects from hosting a super-sized financial sector. For example, Stephen Cecchetti and Enisse Kharroubi of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), have argued that an excessively large financial sector damages productivity and growth.
One reason for that outcome is the distortion of skill allocation. The financial sector, which typically pays more than most others, draws scarce high-level skills away from areas of the economy in which they may contribute more to productivity. When I was director of the London School of Economics, I was struck by the fact that in a school offering a wide range of social sciences and humanities, not simply finance and economics, in some years more than 30% of the graduating class took financial jobs. Many engineering graduates from London’s Imperial College were seduced by investment banks, which paid them extravagantly for inventing elaborate financial structures rather than bridges or machine tools.One reason for that outcome is the distortion of skill allocation. The financial sector, which typically pays more than most others, draws scarce high-level skills away from areas of the economy in which they may contribute more to productivity. When I was director of the London School of Economics, I was struck by the fact that in a school offering a wide range of social sciences and humanities, not simply finance and economics, in some years more than 30% of the graduating class took financial jobs. Many engineering graduates from London’s Imperial College were seduced by investment banks, which paid them extravagantly for inventing elaborate financial structures rather than bridges or machine tools.
A second negative side-effect, according to Cecchetti and Kharroubi, stems from the preference of bank finance for investment in real estate, where collateral is available, rather than less easily assessed investments in technology-based businesses. Their calculations suggest that a high degree of financialisation of the economy, certainly well below the level in the UK in recent years, may impede growth.A second negative side-effect, according to Cecchetti and Kharroubi, stems from the preference of bank finance for investment in real estate, where collateral is available, rather than less easily assessed investments in technology-based businesses. Their calculations suggest that a high degree of financialisation of the economy, certainly well below the level in the UK in recent years, may impede growth.
There is a ring of plausibility to the argument that with finance you can have too much of a good thingThere is a ring of plausibility to the argument that with finance you can have too much of a good thing
Other studies suggest the negative effects begin to be felt when credit to the private sector exceeds 80-100% of GDP. During the financial crisis, the ratio in the UK was around 180% and it had been well over 100% for some time. And others argue that a large finance sector may bolster the exchange rate, making other exports less competitive.Other studies suggest the negative effects begin to be felt when credit to the private sector exceeds 80-100% of GDP. During the financial crisis, the ratio in the UK was around 180% and it had been well over 100% for some time. And others argue that a large finance sector may bolster the exchange rate, making other exports less competitive.
More contentious research recently published by the University of Sheffield goes much further, and attempts to estimate the economic cost incurred as a result of Britain’s specialisation in high finance. The authors arrive at a figure of £4.5tn ($5.9tn), or two years of GDP at 2018 levels, for the period from 1995 to 2015.More contentious research recently published by the University of Sheffield goes much further, and attempts to estimate the economic cost incurred as a result of Britain’s specialisation in high finance. The authors arrive at a figure of £4.5tn ($5.9tn), or two years of GDP at 2018 levels, for the period from 1995 to 2015.
If that analysis is correct, we should be packing bankers off to Paris in specially chartered Eurostar trains, sealed to prevent them from attempting to jump off before they reach the Channel tunnel. Moving Lombard Street to the Boulevard Haussmann could be more effective than any of the other attempts we in England have made to harm our nearest neighbours over the centuries.If that analysis is correct, we should be packing bankers off to Paris in specially chartered Eurostar trains, sealed to prevent them from attempting to jump off before they reach the Channel tunnel. Moving Lombard Street to the Boulevard Haussmann could be more effective than any of the other attempts we in England have made to harm our nearest neighbours over the centuries.
But how robust are these calculations? There is a ring of plausibility to the argument that with finance, as with luxury goods, you can have too much of a good thing. The supposed impact on growth, however, assumes that some of the skilled people shed by the financial sector will move elsewhere in the economy, rather than following the finance jobs wherever they go. There is no guarantee that this will happen, or that employment lost through finance sector moves will be compensated by growth elsewhere. UK manufacturing has underperformed for reasons other than finance, including poor management and bad labour relations.But how robust are these calculations? There is a ring of plausibility to the argument that with finance, as with luxury goods, you can have too much of a good thing. The supposed impact on growth, however, assumes that some of the skilled people shed by the financial sector will move elsewhere in the economy, rather than following the finance jobs wherever they go. There is no guarantee that this will happen, or that employment lost through finance sector moves will be compensated by growth elsewhere. UK manufacturing has underperformed for reasons other than finance, including poor management and bad labour relations.
It looks, however, as though the UK is about to engage in a real-world experiment that tests these theories. Unless there is a surprising breakthrough in the Brexit negotiations, which produces a future free-trade regime for both services and goods, then a substantial relocation of financial activity will occur over time. If and when that happens, we must hope that the BIS economists, derided in London while it was riding high, are not entirely wrong.It looks, however, as though the UK is about to engage in a real-world experiment that tests these theories. Unless there is a surprising breakthrough in the Brexit negotiations, which produces a future free-trade regime for both services and goods, then a substantial relocation of financial activity will occur over time. If and when that happens, we must hope that the BIS economists, derided in London while it was riding high, are not entirely wrong.
• Sir Howard Davies, the first chairman of the UK’s Financial Services Authority (1997-2003), is chairman of RBS. He was director of the London School of Economics (2003-11) and served as deputy governor of the Bank of England and director general of the Confederation of British Industry.• Sir Howard Davies, the first chairman of the UK’s Financial Services Authority (1997-2003), is chairman of RBS. He was director of the London School of Economics (2003-11) and served as deputy governor of the Bank of England and director general of the Confederation of British Industry.
© Project Syndicate© Project Syndicate
Financial sectorFinancial sector
Project Syndicate economistsProject Syndicate economists
EconomicsEconomics
ProductivityProductivity
European UnionEuropean Union
BrexitBrexit
EuropeEurope
Banking
commentcomment
Share on FacebookShare on Facebook
Share on TwitterShare on Twitter
Share via EmailShare via Email
Share on LinkedInShare on LinkedIn
Share on PinterestShare on Pinterest
Share on Google+Share on Google+
Share on WhatsAppShare on WhatsApp
Share on MessengerShare on Messenger
Reuse this contentReuse this content